Monday, April 28, 2008

Do Capital Gains Tax Cuts Raise Revenue? (Part 2)

On April 18th, the Wall Street Journal ran an editorial titled "Obama's Tax Evasion". The editorial mentions the exchange about capital gains between Obama and Charlie Gibson in the prior day's Democratic debate (mentioned in my prior post). It also includes a chart showing the maximum capital gains tax rate and capital gains realizations as a percent of GDP since 1962. I found this data online on the U.S. Treasury's website. The following chart is based on that data.




The actual numbers and sources are at http://www.econdataus.com/cgtax05.html. The above chart appears to match the Wall Street Journal chart except that it contains additional data and goes from 1954 to 2005 (the Wall Street Journal chart goes from 1962 to 2007). The red and dark blue lines in the above chart match the dark blue and light blue lines in the Wall Street Journal chart. About it's chart, the editorial says the following:


As the nearby chart shows, when the tax rate has risen over the past half century, capital gains realizations have fallen and along with them tax revenue. The most recent such episode was in the early 1990s, when Mr. Obama was old enough to be paying attention. That's one reason Jack Kennedy proposed cutting the capital gains rate. And it's one reason Bill Clinton went along with a rate cut to 20% from 28% in 1997.


The mention of the early 1990s would appear to be a misstatement. As can be seen from the above chart, capital gains realizations ROSE in every year from 1991 to 2000 except for a small drop (as a percentage of GDP) in 1994. The author likely meant to reference the increase in the capital gains tax rate in 1986. As the data shows, capital gains realizations nearly doubled from 4.08% of GDP in 1985 to 7.36% of GDP in 1986, just before the increase in the tax rate was to take place. It then dropped back and spent the next nine years around the 2 to 3 percent of GDP range, the range where it was from 1970 to 1982. It would seem clear that the large jump in realization in 1986 was caused by investors taking capital gains before the anticipated rise in the capital gains tax rate. That is one of the major difficulties in studying the effect of capital gains tax rates on revenues. For individual income taxes, it is very difficult to move large amounts of income from one tax year to another in anticipation or in response to a tax rate change. For capital gains taxes, however, this is very easily done by the timing of stock transactions.


In any case, there are a couple of problems with the Wall Street Journal chart. For one thing, it shows the maximum capital gains tax rate but leaves out the descriptor maximum. The chart above also shows the average tax rate. This is the tax rate that one would expect to have the most effect on tax revenue. As can be seen, the average tax rate generally followed the maximum tax rate from the 1986 tax increase on but was relatively stable, not following changes in the maximum tax rate, from 1954 to 1986. I believe that this is because of a major change in the tax law in 1986. As can be seen in this table, capital gains were taxed at the normal income rate before 1986 but with a portion of them (generally 50 to 60 percent of them) excluded from any taxes. After 1986, all capital gains were taxed but at a lower rate. This would appear to have caused more taxpayers to be effected by changes in the capital gains rates after 1986 (thus affecting the average tax rate) than before. In any case, this shows that the changes in the maximum tax rate give little information about what is happening with the average and lower tax rates.


A second problem with the Wall Street Journal chart is that it shows only the capital gains realizations, not the taxes derived from those realizations. The lower yellow line in the above chart shows those revenues. The upper yellow line shows those revenues multiplied by 4 so as to make it easier to compare them with the realizations. As can be seen, this upper yellow line is very close to the realizations (dark blue) line from 1988 through 1996 when the average tax rate was close to 25 percent. However, it dropped well below this line following the 1997 capital gains tax cut when the average tax rate dropped down to about 20 percent. The tax revenues generally follow realizations of course but, since it is the tax revenues that are the chief concern, this is what we should be looking at.


The green line in the above graph shows the common logarithm of the S&P 500 stock index. The logarithm values are useful in showing the index so that a constant percent increase (or decrease) in the index appears as a straight line sloping up (or down). It is useful to look at this index since the level of capital gains realizations is naturally affected by the movement in the market. From 1994 to 2000, the market began to rise sharply and this contributed to the rapid rise in realizations. Likewise, the rapid rise in realization in 2003 was affected by the rise in the market. This relation is somewhat complex as the holding period for realizations vary. For example, an S&P index fund that was bought in 2000 and sold in 2003 would have suffered a large capital loss whereas the same fund held since 1994 would have shown a large capital gain. In any case, the graph of the S&P 500 index gives some visual indication of what was going on in the market prior to any specific tax year.


The above discussion points to how difficult it is to study the relationship between capital gains tax rates and revenues. Hence, it is not intended to show a simple relationship but rather to show the problems with claims of simple relationships derived from looking at a few changes in the capital gains tax rate. That said, I did notice one interesting relationship in the data. From 1954 to 1982, there appeared to have been something of a positive correlation between the average capital gains tax rate and capital gains revenue. That is, they both tended in increase or decrease at the same time. After 1982, there appeared to be much more volatility in both the average tax rate and revenue and any obvious positive correlation disappeared. This would suggest that a more stable average tax rate might be desirable. This would lessen the need for investors to concern themselves with the timing of their stock transactions and allow them to concern themselves only with the long-term value of the investments themselves. If at any point that it is decided that the tax rate needs to be changed, it would likely be wise to phase in the change slowly.


Do Capital Gains Tax Cuts Raise Revenue? (Part 3)

Monday, April 21, 2008

Do Capital Gains Tax Cuts Raise Revenue?

John McCain was the guest on the April 20th program of This Week with George Stephanopoulos. As can be seen in this transcript of the interview, McCain made the following statement about Barack Obama's suggestion that the capital gains tax rate be raised:


And he obviously doesn’t understand the economy, because history shows every time you have cut capital gains taxes, revenues have increased, going back to Jack Kennedy.


It's unclear why McCain mentions Jack Kennedy since, according to this table, there was no change in the capital gains tax rate between 1942 and 1967, four years after Kennedy's death. In any case, George Will expanded on this theme just about one minute into the shows's roundtable segment. Talking about questions that Obama was asked in the April 17th Democratic debate, he said:


One was on capital gains where he conceded the premise of the question as he should because it's true that when you raise capital gains tax rates, you lower revenues from that and he said he'd do it anyway. Even if it reduced the return on American investment, even if it cost the government revenues, he'd do it out of some abstract commitment to fairness.


I thought it odd that Obama would concede that higher capital gains tax rates would bring in less revenues but that he would raise them anyhow. Hence, I checked a transcript of the debate and found the following exchange on page 3:


GIBSON: But history shows that when you drop the capital gains tax, the revenues go up.


OBAMA: Well, that might happen, or it might not. It depends on what's happening on Wall Street and how business is going. I think the biggest problem that we've got on Wall Street right now is the fact that we got have a housing crisis that this president has not been attentive to and that it took John McCain three tries before he got it right.


This is the only point where Obama directly addressed the contention that cutting the capital gains tax rate cause revenues to go up. There is no concession there. Hence, George Will was wrong on that point. What seems more important, however, is the fact that Gibson and Will state the contention that capital gains tax cuts increase revenues as though it is an established tenet of economic theory. Why else would two supposedly objective journalists state it as though it were an accepted fact?


I have previously looked at the effect income tax rate cuts on revenues. My analysis is at http://www.econdataus.com/taxcuts.html. However, I have not looked closely at the effect of capital gains tax rate cuts on revenues. In looking at existing studies, it becomes immediately clear that their positive effect on revenues is far from accepted. In fact, the majority of evidence suggests that they have a negative effect on revenues. An article from the Center on Budget and Policy Priorities list studies by the Congressional Budget Office, Congressional Research Service, and Treasury Department that conclude that capital gains tax rate cuts lose revenues. I did find this Treasury document that projects on page 128 that making the dividends and capital gains tax cuts permanent would cost $196 billion and $104 billion, respectively from 2009 through 2018. Finally, the following excerpt is from a summary of a paper co-authored by N. Gregory Mankiw, former chairman of President Bush’s Council of Economic Advisors and a Harvard economics professor:


According to the researchers, the neoclassical growth model and all of its variants indicate that the dynamic response of the economy to tax changes is substantial. In almost all instances, they find, tax cuts are at least partly self-financing. The authors conduct some simple calculations, plugging in numbers that approximately describe the U.S. economy. They find that, in the long run, about 17 percent of a cut in labor taxes is recouped through higher economic growth. The comparable figure for a cut in capital taxes is about 50 percent. This means that the true revenue cost of a cut in capital taxes is only half of the cost estimated with static scoring.


All of the studies of capital gains tax rate cuts that I've seen seem to agree that they lose revenue. If anyone has seen a study that suggests otherwise, please leave a comment with a link to it. In any event, it's clear that the claim that such cuts increase revenues is, at the very least, heavily contested. I hope that the media will start reporting this issue as such instead of parroting the claim that capital gains tax cuts raise revenue.


Do Capital Gains Tax Cuts Raise Revenue? (Part 2)


Do Capital Gains Tax Cuts Raise Revenue? (Part 3)

About Me

I became interested in U.S. budget and economic matters back in 1992, the first time that I remember the debt becoming a major issue in a presidential election. Along with this blog, I have a website on the subject at http://www.econdataus.com/budget.html. I have blogged further about my motivations for creating this blog and website at this link. Recently, I've been working on replicating studies such as the analysis at this link.

Contact Form

Name

Email *

Message *